In any state, there are a limited
number of effective political parties – parties that actually have power and
influence within the government. Maurice Duverger, a French sociologist,
theorized that the effective number of parties within a state is a function of
that state’s electoral rules, the rules by which members of the legislature are
selected (Sartori). There are two primary democratic systems of electoral
rules: Single-Member-District Plurality, SMDP, and proportional representation,
PR (Shively). Duverger’s Law states that SMDP systems limit the effective
number of parties to two, while PR systems allow multiple parties to be
effective (Sartori).
South Africa has two bodies within
the legislature, but to examine Duverger’s Law, we will use the National
Assembly, the lower house. Parliamentary elections are held every five years,
and members of the National Assembly are elected to five-year terms (Country
Profile). There are 400 seats in the National Assembly, and members are elected
using a closed-list proportional representation system (IPU). Proportional
representation systems primarily gives political parties representation “in the
legislative body…roughly proportional to their strength in the electorate”
(Shively). In a closed-list PR system, the state is divided into different
regions, and political parties provide a ranked list of potential candidates
for office to the election commission. After the election is held, the election
commission “determines the number of seats each party should have, based on its
proportion of the vote, and counts down the ranked list from the top, awarding
places to that number of candidates” (Shively).
Regarding
district magnitude, South Africa has ten multi-member constituencies – one known
as the ‘national’ constituency, while the nine others represent the nine
provinces (IPU). Elections to the National Assembly do not use hybrid electoral
rules, just a closed-list PR system. The formula the South African election commission
uses to allocate legislative seats is known as the Droop quota (Elklit). The
Droop quota formula divides the total amount of votes by the amount of
legislative seats plus one, and then adds one. The resulting number is the
Droop quota. The number of times the Droop quota solidly divides into the
amount of votes for a party is equal to the amount of seats that will be
allocated to the party. In South Africa, this has led to each party winning
four legislative seats for each percentage of the total vote won (IPU).South
African National Assembly elections use proportional representation electoral
rules.
In
South Africa’s 2009 National Assembly elections, twenty-six parties received
votes; however, not all of these parties are effective. Only thirteen of those
parties received seats in parliament, but there aren’t thirteen effective
political parties (South Africa). To calculate the effective number of
political parties, the following equation is used: Neff = 1/Σ(p2), where Neff
is the number of effective parties, and p
is the proportion of the vote each party received (Laakso). In the 2009
parliamentary elections, only four political parties received over 1% of the
vote: African National Congress (ANC), 65.9%; Democratic Alliance (DA), 16.7%;
Congress of the People (COPE), 7.4%; and Inkatha Freedom Party (IFP), 4.55%
(South Africa). These parties are the only ones needed to use in the algorithm.
Once the equation is completed, the resulting number for South Africa is 2.1.
It can be concluded that there are two effective parties within South Africa,
with many smaller parties, accounted for by the .1.
South
Africa’s electoral system, proportional representation, and its number of
effective parties, two, do not support Duverger’s Law. Under Duverger’s Law,
South Africa should have a multiparty system, created from its electoral system
of PR. Instead, South Africa has only two effective parties. While this doesn’t
disprove Duverger’s Law, it contradicts it and does not support it.
CITATIONS
Sartori, Giovanni. Comparative Constitutional Engineering, An Inquiry into
Structures, Incentives and Outcomes. New York: New York UP, 1994. Print.
Shively, W. Phillips. Power & Choice: An Introduction to Political Science. 13th ed. New
York: McGraw Hill, 2012. Print.
"Country Profile: South Africa." ElectionGuide. Consortium for Elections and Political Process
Strengthening (CEPPS), 11 Dec. 2010. Web. 1 Nov. 2012.
"IPU PARLINE Database: SOUTH AFRICA
(National Assembly), Electoral System."PARLINE Database. Inter-Parliamentary Union, 2012. Web. 01 Nov.
2012.
Elklit, Jørgen. "What Electoral Systems Are
Available Out There? An International Perspective on the Current Debate in
South Africa." (2002). Eisa.org.za. Web. 1 Nov. 2012.
"South Africa: 2009 National Assembly
Election Results." EISA. Electoral
Institute for the Sustainability of Democracy in Africa, Apr. 2009. Web. 01
Nov. 2012.
Laakso,
Markku. The "Effective" Number
of Parties: "A Measure with Application to West Europe". Comparative
Political Studies, 12:1 (1979:Apr.) p.3.
Great blog, everything was very clear and you organized your paper very well. Even the Neff's formula was easy to follow.
ReplyDeleteThis was a great post with clear definitions and examples. South Arica has a much different system than the country I studied.
ReplyDeleteYou did a great job, I also did South Africa! My thoughts and findings were just about the same as yours. It's interesting how it doesn't support Duverger's Law. Good work!
ReplyDeleteEverything was well stated, and supported your conclusion. Great job!
ReplyDelete